ISPRS, Vol.34, Part 2W2, “Dynamic and Multi-Dimensional GIS", Bangkok, May 23-25,2001
293
Such additions are too significant to be neglected.
(3) Accessibility of Low-Wage Workers
Job accessibility for low-wage workers deserves special
attention for two factors. The first is the addition of
unemployment (a total of 39,079 in the study area) to the
demand side of labor market. One may argue that workers of
other wage groups may be unemployed too. It is perhaps
reasonable to say that most unemployment competes for the
low-wage jobs. The second is the impact of vehicle
availability. Workers without vehicles have to rely on public
transportation, carpool, walking or bicycles. For simplicity, al
workers without vehicles are assumed to be low-wage
workers 2 , and use public transits. “[Ajccessibility is a
measure of supply, namely potential mobility, is not a
descriptor of behavior.” (Salomon and Mokhtarian, 1998,
p. 131) There are people who choose to use public
transportation or walk or bicycle, not because of their
financial limitation. For workers without vehicles,
dependence on public transits means spending 110.4%
more time than drive-alones for the same commute trips.
Using superscript C or X to differentiate job accessibility for
workers with or without personal vehicles respectively and
superscript 1 to indicate the low-wage group (g=1), equation
(5) can be written as:
•w
7=1
(6)
A}
\x
(7)
where v) =YjS\-r k )w\d k p + r k w[(td kj r p ] for both (6)
¿=i
and (7) since both workers with and without vehicles
compete for the same jobs. Note that W k 1 is the summation
of low-wage workers and unemployment at TAZ k, t is the
time ratio between public transit riders and drive-alones
(t=2.1104 in this study), and r k is the percentage of workers
without personal vehicles at TAZ k. In the Cleveland region
in 1990, 3.75% workers have no vehicles. This is translated
into 12.04% low-wage workers without vehicles.
A combined job accessibility for low-wage workers
is the weighted average of A 1C and A .
A} =Q- n )Aj C + n A} X . (8)
(4) Overall Job Accessibility
Similar to equation (4), the overall (total) job accessibility is
the average of all five accessibility measures weighted by
the number of workers in each wage group:
5. Findings
examine Figure 3 and tell that one place has better job
access than the other. Job proximity and accessibility
indexes discussed in the previous two sections can be used
to evaluate the spatial patterns. See Figures 4 and 5.
Findings are summarized in the following.
(1) Better Job Proximity for Lower-Wage Workers
Job proximity simply reveals how far resident workers are
from their suitable jobs in terms of physical distance. The
index sets the baseline for job accessibility, and represents
perhaps the commonly-perceived locational advantage.
In first question is how job proximity varies among workers of
various wages. In order to address the issue, the 808 TAZs
(excluding 74 TAZs without resident workers) in the study
area are grouped into eight categories based on the mean
wage rates. Table 2 shows the number of TAZs, average job
proximity and other variables (to be discussed) in each
category. A smaller interval ($2,500) is used to divide TAZs
with wage rates of $15,000-$25,000 because many TAZs fall
in the range. From Table 2, the mean wage rate of $30,000
is a turning point. Among the 706 TAZs with mean wage
rates below $30,000, the higher the mean wage rate of a
TAZ, the farther the TAZ is from the jobs (i.e., a larger D
value). Specifically, for TAZs below $20,000, an average
increase of $2,500 in mean wage rate leads to an increase
of about 2-km distance from jobs; for TAZs between
$20,000-30,000, an increase of $5,000 is associated with an
increment of 1,5-2.5 km from job. Among the 102 TAZs with
mean wage rates above the $30,000 level, the trend is
reversed. In all TAZs with mean wage rates lower than
$30,000, TAZs with higher wage rates are farther away from
jobs. This trend is reversed in areas with mean wages above
$30,000.
Table 2. Job Proximity, Accessibility and Others in TAZs with
Various Mean Wage Rates
Mean
Wage
Rate
No.
TAZs
Mean
Job
Proximity
(D, in
km)
Mean Job
Accessibility
(A)
Mean
Commute
Range
(R, km)
Mean
Commute
Time
(minu.)
<
$15k
84
14.98
1.0866
7.51
21.82
$15-
17.5k
144
16.97
1.1194
9.12
22.19
$17.5-
20k
137
18.99
1.0778
10.07
20.84
$20-
22.5k
146
19.96
1.0666
11.41
20.91
$22.5-
25k
108
21.55
0.9876
12.01
21.59
$25-
30k
86
23.03
0.9897
12.83
21.85
$30-
40k
64
21.24
1.0225
12.63
21.85
2:
$40k
38
18.23
1.0404
11.91
20.82
Total
808'
19.30
1.0565
10.72
21.48
'Among the total 882 TAZs, 74 have no resident workers.
Figure 3 shows the job density pattern in 1990. In addition to
the major job concentration in downtown Cleveland, jobs are
scattered across the whole region with several noticeable
suburban concentrations such as Lorain downtown,
Cleveland International Airport, Solon Industrial Parks and a
service office center in southeast. One cannot simply
2 The CTPP does not have the information of vehicle
availability by wage groups. The data of vehicle availability
by household incomes indicate that only low-income
households face the problem of no vehicles.
In the classic urban economic model, locations of workers
are determined by the tradeoff between transportation and
housing costs. On the one side, higher-income workers
could live farther away from jobs than lower-income earners
if their saving in housing cost exceeds the increased cost in
commuting. On the other side, the relationship could be
reversed if the increase in commuting cost is more than the
saving from housing. The above analysis supports that
higher-wage workers live farther from jobs up to a certain
wage level. Beyond that, high-wage workers value the time