ISPRS, Vol.34, Part 2W2, “Dynamic and Multi-Dimensional GIS”, Bangkok, May 23-25. 2001
295
First, among areas with mean wage rates below $30,000,
the higher the mean wage rate in a residential area, the
farther the area is away from the jobs (i.e., workers trade
better housing or more space for longer commutes). In areas
above $30,000, the trend is reversed. That is to say, low-
wage workers are indeed located in proximity to their
suitable jobs. Porter (1995) characterizes this as the
competitive advantage of inner-city low-income residents.
Public policies should be directed to help them utilize not
abandon their locational advantage (Shen, 1998, p.358).
Second, although low-wage workers enjoy better job
proximity in general, many of the inner-city residents have
the worst job accessibility. Policies for improving the job
accessibility of these residents should focus on removing the
nonspatial barriers that handicap their mobility, such as
enhancing vehicle ownership and availability, and improving
the road network, traffic conditions and public transit
services near their residences. Attempts such as relocating
them to suburban housing or similar settings may receive
disappointed results.
Third, the mean commute time varies little among areas with
different mean wage rates. But workers of high-wage
residential areas have far better mobility than those of low-
wage areas. In other words, high-wage workers are able to
travel faster probably because of their easy access to
highways and less congestion in low-density areas. But the
time saved through faster travel is not translated into non
travel activities but into greater distance traveled (Bieber et
al., 1994). Better mobility means larger search ranges and
more choices of jobs and housing opportunities. The
literature tends to pay more attention to explanations and
policy implications of commute time. Mobility (i.e., commute
range) deserves more attention.
Finally, jobs are scattered regionwide with several significant
suburban job concentrations. However, downtown Cleveland
exerts the dominant effect on forming the concentric patterns
of job proximity (to a less degree, job accessibility). Since
workers with various wages respond differently to job
access, the mean wage distribution is hardly monocentric.
The urban classic monocentric model assumes the CBD as
the only employment location, and considers income as the
driving force shaping the residential concentric patterns. This
research lends support to the monocentric model in terms of
job access (the cause), not the spatial pattern of income
distribution (the consequence). The complicated urban
mosaic is, at least partially, explainable by the nonlinear
response of commute ranges to increasing wages.
For the reasons discussed in the introduction section
(particularly the focus of classic urban economic models on
income to explain residential locations), this research
examines on the job proximity and accessibility for workers
of various wage groups. Perhaps the major weakness of the
research is its failure to consider other socioeconomic
factors such as race, education and family structure. Future
research will be pursued in those directions.
RERERENCE9
Bieber, A., M. H. Massot and J. P. Orfeuil. 1994. Prospects
for daily urban mobility. Transport Reviews 14,
321-339.
Bureau of Transportation Statistics, U.S. Department of
Transportation. 1996. The 1990 Census for
Transportation Planning Package (Urban
Element), BTS-CD-15-08.
Cervero R., K. L. Wu. 1998. Sub-centring and commuting:
Evidence from the San Francisco Bay Area, 1980-
90. Urban Studies 35, 1059-1076.
Environmental Systems Research Institute, Inc. (ESRI)
2000.
http://vvww.esri com 'dataonline/tiaer.'index.html.
Ellwood, D. T. 1986. The spatial mismatch hypothesis: are
there teenage jobs missing in the ghetto? In R. B.
Freeman and H. J. Holer (eds), The Black Youth
Employment Crisis, Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 147-185.
Freeman, R. B. 1996. Why do so many young American
men commit crimes and what might we do about
it? Journal of Economic Perspectives 10, 25-43.
Gordon P., H. Richardson, M. Jun. 1991. The commuting
paradox: evidence from the top twenty. Journal of
American Planning Association 57, 416-420.
Hansen, W. G. 1959. How accessibility shapes land use.
Journal of the American Institute of Planners 25,
73-76.
Huff, D. L. 1963. A probabilistic analysis of shopping center
trade areas. Land Economics 39, 81 -90.
Ihlanfeldt K. R. and D. L. Sjoquist. 1990. Job accessibility
and racial differences in youth employment rates.
The American Economic Review 80, 267-276.
Immergluck, D. 1998. Job proximity and the urban
employment problem: Do suitable nearby jobs
improve neighborhood employment rates? Urban
Studies 35, 7-23.
Kain, J. 1968. Housing segregation, Negro employment, and
metropolitan decentralization. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 82, 175-197.
Leete, L, N. Bania and C. Coulton. 2000. Updated estimates
of entry-level job openings in the eight-county
Cleveland Akron Metropolitan Area. Briefing
Report No. 9910, Center on Urban Poverty and
Social Change, Case Western Reserve University.
Porter, M. 1995. The competitive advantage of the inner city.
Harvard Business Review (May-June),
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 55-71.
Salomon, I. and P. L. Mokhtarian. 1998. What happens
when mobility-inclined market segments face
accessibility-enhancing policies? Transportation
Research 03,129-140.
Sawicki, D. S. and M. Moody. 2000. Developing
transportation alternatives for welfare recipients
moving to work. Journal of the American Planning
Association 66, 306-318.
Sen, A., P. Metaxatos, S. Soot and V. Thakyriah, 1999.
Welfare reform and spatial matching between
clients and jobs. Papers in Regional Science 78,
195-211.
Shen, Q. 1998. Location characteristics of inner-city
neighborhoods and employment accessibility of
low-income workers. Environment and Planning B:
Planning and Design 25, 345-365.
Shen, Q. 1999. Transportation, telecommunications, and the
changing geography of opportunity. Urban
Geography 20, 334-355.
Shen, Q. 2000. Spatial and social dimensions of commuting.
Journal of the American Planning Association 66,
68-82.
Taylor, B. and P. Ong. 1995. Spatial mismatch or automobile
mismatch? An examination of race, residence and
commuting in U.S. metropolitan areas. Urban
Studies 32, 1453-1473.
Wang, F. and W. Minor. 2000. Is job accessibility relevant to
crime patterns?: A GIS approach. Final Report to
the National Institute of Justice (NIJ) [available
upon request from the NIJ].
Wang, F. 2000. Modeling commute patterns in Chicago in a
GIS environment: a job accessibility perspective.
Professional Geographer 52,120-133.
Wang, F. 2001. Explaining Intraurban Variations of
Commuting by Job Accessibility and Workers’
Characteristics, Environment and Planning B, in
press.
Wilson, W. J. 1996. When Work Disappears. New York:
Alfred A Knopf.